Chapter 22
NOTES ON THE TRADE CYCLE
Since we claim to have shown in the preceding chapters what
determines the volume of employment at any time, it follows, if
we are right, that our theory must be capable of explaining the
phenomena of the trade cycle.
If we examine the details of any actual instance of the trade
cycle, we shall find that it is highly complex and that every
element in our analysis will be required for its complete
explanation. In particular we shall find that fluctuations in the
propensity to consume, in the state of liquidity-preference, and
in the marginal efficiency of capital have all played a part. But
I suggest that the essential character of the trade cycle and,
especially, the regularity of time-sequence and of duration which
justifies us in calling it a cycle, is mainly due to the
way in which the marginal efficiency of capital fluctuates. The
trade cycle is best regarded, I think, as being occasioned by a
cyclical change in the marginal efficiency of capital, though
complicated and often aggravated by associated changes in the
other significant short-period variables of the economic system.
To develop this thesis would occupy a book rather than a chapter,
and would require a close examination of facts. But the following
short notes will be sufficient to indicate the line of
investigation which our preceding theory suggests.
I
By a cyclical movement we mean that as the system
progresses in, e.g. the upward direction, the forces propelling it upwards at first gather force and have a
cumulative effect on one another but gradually lose their
strength until at a certain point they tend to be replaced by
forces operating in the opposite direction; which in turn gather
force for a time and accentuate one another, until they too,
having reached their maximum development, wane and give place to
their opposite. We do not, however, merely mean by a cyclical movement
that upward and downward tendencies, once started, do not persist
for ever in the same direction but are ultimately reversed. We
mean also that there is some recognisable degree of regularity in
the time-sequence and duration of the upward and downward
movements.
There is, however, another characteristic of what we call the
trade cycle which our explanation must cover if it is to be
adequate; namely, the phenomenon of the crisis¾the fact that the substitution of a
downward for an upward tendency often takes place suddenly and
violently, whereas there is, as a rule, no such sharp
turning-point when an upward is substituted for a downward
tendency.
Any fluctuation in investment not offset by a
corresponding change in the propensity to consume will, of
course, result in a fluctuation in employment. Since, therefore,
the volume of investment is subject to highly complex influences,
it is highly improbable that all fluctuations either in
investment itself or in the marginal efficiency of capital will
be of a cyclical character. One special case, in particular,
namely, that which is associated with agricultural fluctuations,
will be separately considered in a later section of this chapter.
I suggest, however, that there are certain definite reasons why,
in the case of a typical industrial trade cycle in the
nineteenth-century environment, fluctuations in the marginal
efficiency of capital should have had cyclical characteristics.
These reasons are by no means unfamiliar either in themselves or
as explanations of the trade cycle. My only purpose here is to link them up with the
preceding theory.
II
I can best introduce what I have to say by beginning with the
later stages of the boom and the onset of the 'crisis'.
We have seen above that the marginal efficiency of
capital depends, not only on the existing abundance or scarcity of
capital-goods and the current cost of production of
capital-goods, but also on current expectations as to the future
yield of capital-goods. In the case of durable assets it is,
therefore, natural and reasonable that expectations of the future
should play a dominant part in determining the scale on which new
investment is deemed advisable. But, as we have seen, the basis
for such expectations is very precarious. Being based on shifting
and unreliable evidence, they are subject to sudden and violent
changes.
Now, we have been accustomed in explaining the 'crisis' to lay
stress on the rising tendency of the rate of interest under the
influence of the increased demand for money both for trade and
speculative purposes. At times this factor may certainly play an
aggravating and, occasionally perhaps, an initiating part. But I
suggest that a more typical, and often the predominant,
explanation of the crisis is, not primarily a rise in the rate of
interest, but a sudden collapse in the marginal efficiency of
capital.
The later stages of the boom are characterised by optimistic
expectations as to the future yield of capital-goods sufficiently
strong to offset their growing abundance and their rising costs
of production and, probably, a rise in the rate of interest also.
It is of the nature of organised investment markets, under the influence of
purchasers largely ignorant of what they are buying and of
speculators who are more concerned with forecasting the next
shift of market sentiment than with a reasonable estimate of the
future yield of capital-assets, that, when disillusion falls upon
an over-optimistic and over-bought market, it should fall with
sudden and even catastrophic force.
Nloreover, the dismay and uncertainty as to the future which
accompanies a collapse in the marginal efficiency of capital
naturally precipitates a sharp increase in liquidity-preference¾and hence a rise in the rate of interest.
Thus the fact that a collapse in the marginal efficiency of
capital tends to be associated with a rise in the rate of
interest may seriously aggravate the decline in investment. But
the essence of the situation is to be found, nevertheless, in the
collapse in the marginal efficiency of capital, particularly in
the case of those types of capital which have been contributing
most to the previous phase of heavy new investment.
Liquidity-preference, except those manifestations of it which are
associated with increasing trade and speculation, does not
increase until after the collapse in the marginal
efficiency of capital.
It is this, indeed, which renders the slump so intractable.
Later on, a decline in the rate of interest will be a great aid
to recovery and, probably, a necessary condition of it. But, for
the moment, the collapse in the marginal efficiency of capital
may be so complete that no practicable reduction in the rate of
interest will be enough. If a reduction in the rate of interest
was capable of proving an effective remedy by itself; it might be
possible to achieve a recovery without the elapse of any
considerable interval of time and by means more or less directly
under the control of the monetary authority. But, in fact, this is not usually the case; and it
is not so easy to revive the marginal efficiency of capital,
determined, as it is, by the uncontrollable and disobedient
psychology of the business world. It is the return of confidence,
to speak in ordinary language, which is so insusceptible to
control in an economy of individualistic capitalism. This is the
aspect of the slump which bankers and business men have been
right in emphasising, and which the economists who have put their
faith in a 'purely monetary' remedy have underestimated.
This brings me to my point. The explanation of the
time-element in the trade cycle, of the fact that an interval of
time of a particular order of magnitude must usually elapse
before recovery begins, is to be sought in the influences which
govern the recovery of the marginal efficiency of capital. There
are reasons, given firstly by the length of life of durable
assets in relation to the normal rate of growth in a given epoch,
and secondly by the carrying-costs of surplus stocks, why the
duration of the downward movement should have an order of
magnitude which is not fortuitous, which does not fluctuate
between, say, one year this time and ten years next time, but
which shows some regularity of habit between, let us say, three
and five years.
Let us recur to what happens at the crisis. So long as the
boom was continuing, much of the new investment showed a not
unsatisfactory current yield. The disillusion comes because
doubts suddenly arise concerning the reliability of the
prospective yield, perhaps because the current yield shows signs
of falling off, as the stock of newly produced durable goods
steadily increases. If current costs of production are thought to
be higher than they will be later on, that will be a further
reason for a fall in the marginal efficiency of capital. Once
doubt begins it spreads rapidly. Thus at the outset of the slump
there is probably much capital of which the marginal efficiency
has become negligible or even negative. But the interval of time, which will have to elapse
before the shortage of capital through use, decay and
obsolescence causes a sufficiently obvious scarcity to increase
the marginal efficiency, may be a somewhat stable function of the
average durability of capital in a given epoch. If the
characteristics of the epoch shift, the standard time-interval
will change. If, for example, we pass from a period of increasing
population into one of declining population, the characteristic
phase of the cycle will be lengthened. But we have in the above a
substantial reason why the duration of the slump should have a
definite relationship to the length of life of durable assets and
to the normal rate of growth in a given epoch.
The second stable time-factor is due to the carrying-costs of
surplus stocks which force their absorption within a certain
period, neither very short nor very long. The sudden cessation of
new investment after the crisis will probably lead to an
accumulation of surplus stocks of unfinished goods. The
carrying-costs of these stocks will seldom be less than 10 per
cent. per annum. Thus the fall in their price needs to be
sufficient to bring about a restriction which provides for their
absorption within a period of; say, three to five years at the
outside. Now the process of absorbing the stocks represents
negative investment, which is a further deterrent to employment;
and, when it is over, a manifest relief will be experienced.
Moreover, the reduction in working capital, which is necessarily
attendant on the decline in output on the downward phase,
represents a further element of disinvestment, which may be
large; and, once the recession has begun, this exerts a strong
cumulative influence in the downward direction. In the earliest
phase of a typical slump there will probably be an investment in
increasing stocks which helps to offset disinvestment in
working-capital; in the next phase there may be a short period of
disinvestment both in stocks and in working-capital; after the lowest point has been passed there is
likely to be a further disinvestment in stocks which partially
offsets reinvestment in working-capital; and, finally, after the
recovery is well on its way, both factors will be simultaneously
favourable to investment. It is against this background that the
additional and superimposed effects of fluctuations of investment
in durable goods must be examined. When a decline in this type of
investment has set a cyclical fluctuation in motion there will be
little encouragement to a recovery in such investment until the
cycle has partly run its course.
Unfortunately a serious fall in the marginal efficiency of
capital also tends to affect adversely the propensity to consume.
For it involves a severe decline in the market value of stock
exchange equities. Now, on the class who take an active interest
in their stock exchange investments, especially if they are
employing borrowed funds, this naturally exerts a very depressing
influence. These people are, perhaps, even more influenced in
their readiness to spend by rises and falls in the value of their
investments than by the state of their incomes. With a
'stock-minded' public as in the United States to-day, a rising
stock-market may be an almost essential condition of a
satisfactory propensity to consume; and this circumstance,
generally overlooked until lately, obviously serves to aggravate
still further the depressing effect of a decline in the marginal
efficiency of capital.
When once the recovery has been started, the manner in which
it feeds on itself and cumulates is obvious. But during the
downward phase, when both fixed capital and stocks of materials
are for the time being redundant and working-capital is being
reduced, the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital may
fall so low that it can scarcely be corrected, so as to secure a satisfactory rate of new investment, by any
practicable reduction in the rate of interest. Thus with markets
organised and influenced as they are at present, the market
estimation of the marginal efficiency of capital may suffer such
enormously wide fluctuations that it cannot be sufficiently
offset by corresponding fluctuations in the rate of interest.
Moreover, the corresponding movements in the stock-market may, as
we have seen above, depress the propensity to consume just wlaen
it is most needed. In conditions of laissez-faire the
avoidance of wide fluctuations in employment may, therefore,
prove impossible without a far-reaching change in the psychology
of investment markets such as there is no reason to expect. I
conclude that the duty of ordering the current volume of
investment cannot safely be left in private hands.
III
The preceding analysis may appear to be in conformity with the
view of those who hold that over-investment is the characteristic
of the boom, that the avoidance of this over-investment is the
only possible remedy for the ensuing slump, and that, whilst for
the reasons given above the slump cannot be prevented by a low
rate of interest, nevertheless the boom can be avoided by a high
rate of interest. There is, indeed, force in the argument that a
high rate of interest is much more effective against a boom than
a low rate of interest against a slump.
To infer these conclusions from the above would, however,
misinterpret my analysis; and would, according to my way of
thinking, involve serious error. For the term over-investment is
ambiguous. It may refer to investments which are destined to
disappoint the expectations which prompted them or for which
there is no use in conditions of severe unemployment, or it may
indicate a state of affairs where every kind of capital-goods is so abundant that there is no new investment which is
expected, even in conditions of full employment, to earn in the
course of its life more than its replacement cost. It is only the
latter state of affairs which is one of over-investment, strictly
speaking, in the sense that any further investment would be a
sheer waste of resources.
Moreover, even if over-investment in this sense was a normal
characteristic of the boom, the remedy would not lie in clapping
on a high rate of interest which would probably deter some useful
investments and might further diminish the propensity to consume,
but in taking drastic steps, by redistributing incomes or
otherwise, to stimulate the propensity to consume.
According to my analysis, however, it is only in the former
sense that the boom can be said to be characterised by
over-investment. The situation, which I am indicating as typical,
is not one in which capital is so abundant that the community as
a whole has no reasonable use for any more, but where investment
is being made in conditions which are unstable and cannot endure,
because it is prompted by expectations which are destined to
disappointment.
It may, of course, be the case¾indeed
it is likely to be¾that the illusions
of the boom cause particular types of capital-assets to be
produced in such excessive abundance that some part of the output
is, on any criterion, a waste of resources;¾which
sometimes happens, we may add, even when there is no boom. It
leads, that is to say, to misdirected investment. But over
and above this it is an essential characteristic of the boom that
investments which will in fact yield, say, 2 per cent in
conditions of full employment are made in the expectation of a
yield of; say, 6 per cent, and are valued accordingly. When the
disillusion comes, this expectation is replaced by a contrary 'error of pessimism', with the result
that the investments, which would in fact yield 2 per cent in
conditions of full employment, are expected to yield less than
nothing; and the resulting collapse of new investment then leads
to a state of unemployment in which the investments, which would
have yielded 2 per cent in conditions of full employment, in fact
yield less than nothing. We reach a condition where there is a
shortage of houses, but where nevertheless no one can afford to
live in the houses that there are.
Thus the remedy for the boom is not a higher rate of interest
but a lower rate of interest!
For that may enable the so-called boom to last. The right remedy
for the trade cycle is not to be found in abolishing booms and
thus keeping us permanently in a semi-slump; but in abolishing
slumps and thus keeping us permanently in a quasi-boom.
The boom which is destined to end in a slump is caused,
therefore, by the combination of a rate of interest, which in a
correct state of expectation would be too high for full
employment, with a misguided state of expectation which, so long
as it lasts, prevents this rate of interest from being in fact
deterrent. A boom is a situation in which over-optimism triumphs
over a rate of interest which, in a cooler light, would be seen
to be excessive.
Except during the war, I doubt if we have any recent
experience of a boom so strong that it led to full employment. In
the United States employment was very satisfactory in 1928-29 on normal standards; but I have seen no
evidence of a shortage of labour, except, perhaps, in the case of
a few groups of highly specialised workers. Some 'bottle-necks'
were reached, but output as a whole was still capable of further
expansion. Nor was there over-investment in the sense that the standard and equipment of housing was so high that everyone,
assuming full employment, had all he wanted at a rate which would
no more than cover the replacement cost, without any allowance
for interest, over the life of the house; and that transport,
public services and agricultural improvement had been carried to
a point where further additions could not reasonably be expected
to yield even their replacement cost. Quite the contrary. It
would be absurd to assert of the United States in 1929 the
existence of over-investment in the strict sense. The true state
of affairs was of a different character. New investment during
the previous five years had been, indeed, on so enormous a scale
in the aggregate that the prospective yield of further additions
was, coolly considered, falling rapidly. Correct foresight would
have brought down the marginal efficiency of capital to an
unprecedentedly low figure; so that the 'boom' could not have
continued on a sound basis except with a very low long-term rate
of interest, and an avoidance of misdirected investment in the
particular directions which were in danger of being
over-exploited. In fact, the rate of interest was high enough to
deter new investment except in those particular directions which
were under the influence of speculative excitement and,
therefore, in special danger of being over-exploited; and a rate
of interest, high enough to overcome the speculative excitement,
would have checked, at the same time, every kind of reasonable
new investment. Thus an increase in the rate of interest, as a
remedy for the state of affairs arising out of a prolonged period
of abnormally heavy new investment, belongs to the species of
remedy which cures the disease by killing the patient.
It is, indeed, very possible that the prolongation of
approximately full employment over a period of years would be
associated in countries so wealthy as Great Britain or the United
States with a volume of new investment, assuming the existing
propensity to consume, so great that it would eventually lead to a state of
full investment in the sense that an aggregate gross yield in
excess of replacement cost could no longer be expected on a
reasonable calculation from a further increment of durable goods
of any type whatever. Moreover, this situation might be reached
comparatively soon¾say within
twenty-five years or less. I must not be taken to deny this,
because I assert that a state of full investment in the strict
sense has never yet occurred, not even momentarily.
Furthermore, even if we were to suppose that contemporary
booms are apt to be associated with a momentary condition of full
investment or over-investment in the strict sense, it would still
be absurd to regard a higher rate of interest as the appropriate
remedy. For in this event the case of those who attribute the
disease to under-consumption would be wholly established. The
remedy would lie in various measures designed to increase the
propensity to consume by the redistribution of incomes or
otherwise; so that a given level of employment would require a
smaller volume of current investment to support it.
IV
It may be convenient at this point to say a word about the
important schools of thought which maintain, from various points
of view, that the chronic tendency of contemporary societies to
under-employment is to be traced to under-consumption;¾that is to say, to social practices and to
a distribution of wealth which result in a propensity to consume
which is unduly low.
In existing conditions¾or, at
least, in the condition which existed until lately¾where the volume of investment is
unplanned and uncontrolled, subject to the vagaries of the
marginal efficiency of capital as determined by the private
judgment of individuals ignorant or speculative, and to a long-term rate of interest which
seldom or never falls below a conventional level, these schools
of thought are, as guides to practical policy, undoubtedly in the
right. For in such conditions there is no other means of raising
the average level of employment to a more satisfactory level. If
it is impracticable materially to increase investment, obviously
there is no means of securing a higher level of employment except
by increasing consumption.
Practically I only differ from these schools of thought in
thinking that they may lay a little too much emphasis on
increased consumption at a time when there is still much social
advantage to be obtained from increased investment.
Theoretically, however, they are open to the criticism of
neglecting the fact that there are two ways to expand output.
Even if we were to decide that it would be better to increase
capital more slowly and to concentrate effort on increasing
consumption, we must decide this with open eyes after well
considering the alternative. I am myself impressed by the great
social advantages of increasing the stock of capital until it
ceases to be scarce. But this is a practical judgment, not a
theoretical imperative.
Moreover, I should readily concede that the wisest course is
to advance on both fronts at once. Whilst aiming at a socially
controlled rate of investment with a view to a progressive
decline in the marginal efficiency of capital, I should support
at the same time all sorts of policies for increasing the
propensity to consume. For it is unlikely that full employment
can be maintained, whatever we may do about investment, with the
existing propensity to consume. There is room, therefore, for
both policies to operate together;¾to
promote investment and, at the same time, to promote consumption,
not merely to the level which with the existing propensity to
consume would correspond to the increased investment, but to a
higher level still. If¾to take round
figures for the purpose of illustration¾the average level of
output of to-day is 15 per cent below what it would be with
continuous full employment, and if 10 per cent of this output
represents net investment and 90 per cent of it consumption¾if, furthermore, net investment would have
to rise 50 per cent in order to secure full employment with the
existing propensity to consume, so that with full employment
output would rise from 100 to 115, consumption from 90 to 100 and
net investment from 10 to 15:¾then we
might aim, perhaps, at so modifying the propensity to consume
that with full employment consumption would rise from 90 to 103
and net investment from 10 to 12.
V
Another school of thought finds the solution of the trade
cycle, not in increasing either consumption or investment, but in
diminishing the supply of labour seeking employment; i.e. by
redistributing the existing volume of employment without
increasing employment or output.
This seems to me to be a premature policy¾much
more clearly so than the plan of increasing consumption. A point
comes where every individual weighs the advantages of increased
leisure against increased income. But at present the evidence is,
I think, strong that the great majority of individuals would
prefer increased income to increased leisure; and I see no
sufficient reason for compelling those who would prefer more
income to enjoy more leisure.
VI
It may appear extraordinary that a school of thought should
exist which finds the solution for the trade cycle in checking
the boom in its early stages by a higher rate of interest. The
only line of argument, along which any justification for this
policy can be discovered, is that put forward by Mr D. H. Robertson,
who assumes, in effect, that full employment is an impracticable
ideal and that the best that we can hope for is a level of
employment much more stable than at present and averaging,
perhaps, a little higher.
If we rule out major changes of policy affecting either the
control of investment or the propensity to consume, and assume,
broadly speaking, a continuance of the existing state of affairs,
it is, I think, arguable that a more advantageous average state
of expectation might result from a banking policy which always
nipped in the bud an incipient boom by a rate of interest high
enough to deter even the most misguided optimists. The
disappointment of expectation, characteristic of the slump, may
lead to so much loss and waste that the average level of useful
investment might be higher if a deterrent is applied. It is
difficult to be sure whether or not this is correct on its own
assumptions; it is a matter for practical judgment where detailed
evidence is wanting. It may be that it overlooks the social
advantage which accrues from the increased consumption which
attends even on investment which proves to have been totally
misdirected, so that even such investment may be more beneficial
than no investment at all. Nevertheless, the most enlightened
monetary control might find itself in difficulties, faced with a
boom of the 1929 type in America, and armed with no other weapons
than those possessed at that time by the Federal Reserve System;
and none of the alternatives within its power might make much
difference to the result. However this may be, such an outlook
seems to me to be dangerously and unnecessarily defeatist. It
recommends, or at least assumes, for permanent acceptance too
much that is defective in our existing economic scheme.
The austere view, which would employ a high rate of interest
to check at once any tendency in the level of employment to rise
appreciably above the average of; say, the previous decade, is, however, more usually
supported by arguments which have no foundation at all apart from
confusion of mind. It flows, in some cases, from the belief that
in a boom investment tends to outrun saving, and that a higher
rate of interest will restore equilibrium by checking investment
on the one hand and stimulating savings on the other. This
implies that saving and investment can be unequal, and has,
therefore, no meaning until these terms have been defined in some
special sense. Or it is sometimes suggested that the increased
saving which accompanies increased investment is undesirable and
unjust because it is, as a rule, also associated with rising
prices. But if this were so, any upward change in the
existing level of output and employment is to be deprecated. For
the rise in prices is not essentially due to the increase in
investment;¾it is due to the fact
that in the short period supply price usually increases with
increasing output, on account either of the physical fact of
diminishing return or of the tendency of the cost-unit to rise in
terms of money when output increases. If the conditions were
those of constant supply-price, there would, of course, be no
rise of prices; yet, all the same, increased saving would
accompany increased investment. It is the increased output which
produces the increased saving; and the rise of prices is merely a
by-product of the increased output, which will occur equally if
there is no increased saving but, instead, an increased
propensity to consume. No one has a legitimate vested interest in
being able to buy at prices which are only low because output is
low.
Or, again, the evil is supposed to creep in if the increased
investment has been promoted by a fall in the rate of interest
engineered by an increase in the quantity of money. Yet there is
no special virtue in the pre-existing rate of interest, and the
new money is not 'forced' on anyone;¾it
is created in order to satisfy the increased liquidity-preference
which corresponds to the lower rate of interest or the increased volume
of transactions, and it is held by those individuals who prefer
to hold money rather than to lend it at the lower rate of
interest. Or, once more, it is suggested that a boom is
characterised by 'capital consumption', which presumably means
negative net investment, i.e. by an excessive propensity to
consume. Unless the phenomena of the trade cycle have been
confused with those of a flight from the currency such as
occurred during the post-war European currency collapses, the
evidence is wholly to the contrary. Moreover, even if it were so,
a reduction in the rate of interest would be a more plausible
remedy than a rise in the rate of interest for conditions of
under-investment. I can make no sense at all of these schools of
thought; except, perhaps, by supplying a tacit assumption that
aggregate output is incapable of change. But a theory which
assumes constant output is obviously not very serviceable for
explaining the trade cycle.
VII
In the earlier studies of the trade cycle, notably by J evons,
an explanation was found in agricultural fluctuations due to the
seasons, rather than in the phenomena of industry. In the light
of the above theory this appears as an extremely plausible
approach to the problem. For even to-day fluctuation in the
stocks of agricultural products as between one year and another
is one of the largest individual items amongst the causes of
changes in the rate of current investment; whilst at the time
when Jevons wrote¾and more
particularly over the period to which most of his statistics
applied¾this factor must have far
outweighed all others. Jevons's theory, that the trade cycle was
primarily due to the fluctuations in the bounty of the harvest,
can be re-stated as follows. When an exceptionally large harvest
is gathered in, an important addition is usually made to the quantity carried over into later years. The
proceeds of this addition are added to the current incomes of the
farmers and are treated by them as income; whereas the increased
carry-over involves no drain on the income-expenditure of other
sections of the community but is financed out of savings. That is
to say, the addition to the carry-over is an addition to current
investment. This conclusion is not invalidated even if prices
fall sharply. Similarly when there is a poor harvest, the
carry-over is drawn upon for current consumption, so that a
corresponding part of the income-expenditure of the consumers
creates no current income for the farmers. That is to say, what
is taken from the carry-over involves a corresponding reduction
in current investment. Thus, if investment in other directions is
taken to be constant, the difference in aggregate investment
between a year in which there is a substantial addition to the
carry-over and a year in which there is a substantial subtraction
from it may be large; and in a community where agriculture is the
predominant industry it will be overwhelmingly large compared
with any other usual cause of investment fluctuations. Thus it is
natural that we should find the upward turning-point to be marked
by bountiful harvests and the downward turning-point by deficient
harvests. The further theory, that there are physical causes for
a regular cycle of good and bad harvests, is, of course, a
different matter with which we are not concerned here.
More recently, the theory has been advanced that it is bad
harvests, not good harvests, which are good for trade, either
because bad harvests make the population ready to work for a
smaller real reward or because the resulting redistribution of
purchasing-power is held to be favourable to consumption.
Needless to say, it is not these theories which I have in mind in
the above description of harvest phenomena as an explanation of
the trade cycle.
The agricultural causes of fluctuation are, however, much less
important in the modern world for two reasons. In the first place
agricultural output is a much smaller proportion of total output.
And in the second place the development of a world market for
most agricultural products, drawing upon both hemispheres, leads
to an averaging out of the effects of good and bad seasons, the
percentage fluctuation in the amount of the world harvest being
far less than the percentage fluctuations in the harvests of
individual countries. But in old days, when a country was mainly
dependent on its own harvest, it is difficult to see any possible
cause of fluctuations in investment, except war, which was in any
way comparable in magnitude with changes in the carry-over of
agricultural products.
Even to-day it is important to pay close attention to the part
played by changes in the stocks of raw materials, both
agricultural and mineral, in the determination of the rate of
current investment. I should attribute the slow rate of recovery
from a slump, after the turning-point has been reached, mainly to
the deflationary effect of the reduction of redundant stocks to a
normal level. At first the accumulation of stocks, which occurs
after the boom has broken, moderates the rate of the collapse;
but we have to pay for this relief later on in the damping-down
of the subsequent rate of recovery. Sometimes, indeed, the
reduction of stocks may have to be virtually completed before any
measurable degree of recovery can be detected. For a rate of
investment in other directions, which is sufficient to produce an
upward movement when there is no current disinvestment in stocks
to set off against it, may be quite inadequate so long as such
disinvestment is still proceeding.
We have seen, I think, a signal example of this in the earlier
phases of America's 'New Deal'. When President Roosevelt's
substantial loan expenditure began, stocks of all kinds¾and particularly of agricultural products¾still stood at a
very high level. The 'New Deal' partly consisted in a strenuous
attempt to reduce these stocks¾by
curtailment of current output and in all sorts of ways. The
reduction of stocks to a normal level was a necessary process¾a phase which had to be endured. But so
long as it lasted, namely, about two years, it constituted a
substantial offset to the loan expenditure which was being
incurred in other directions. Only when it had been completed was
the way prepared for substantial recovery.
Recent American experience has also afforded good examples of
the part played by fluctuations in the stocks of finished and
unfinished goods¾'inventories' as it
is becoming usual to call them¾in
causing the minor oscillations within the main movement of the
trade cycle. Manufacturers, setting industry in motion to provide
for a scale of consumption which is expected to prevail some
months later, are apt to make minor miscalculations, generally in
the direction of running a little ahead of the facts. When they
discover their mistake they have to contract for a short time to
a level below that of current consumption so as to allow for the
absorption of the excess inventories; and the difference of pace
between running a little ahead and dropping back again has proved
sufficient in its effect on the current rate of investment to
display itself quite clearly against the background of the
excellently complete statistics now available in the United
States.