Chapter 20
THE EMPLOYMENT FUNCTION
I
In chapter 3 (Chapter 3
) we have defined the aggregate supply function Z =
f(N), which relates the employment
N
with the aggregate supply price of the corresponding output. The
employment
function only differs from the aggregate supply function in that it
is, in effect, its inverse function and is defined in terms of the wage-unit;
the object of the employment function being to relate the amount of the
effective demand, measured in terms of the wage-unit, directed to a given
firm or industry or to industry as a whole with the amount of employment,
the supply price of the output of which will compare to that amount of
effective demand. Thus if an amount of effective demand
Dwr,
measured in wage-units, directed to a firm or industry calls forth an amount
of employment Nr in that firm or industry, the employment
function is given by Nr = Fr(Dwr).
Or, more generally, if we are entitled to assume that Dwr
is a unique function of the total effective demand Dw,
the employment function is given by Nr = Fr(Dw)
That is to say, Nr men will be employed in industry r
when effective demand is Dw.
We shall develop in this chapter certain properties of the employment
function. But apart from any interest which these may have, there are two
reasons why the substitution of the employment function for the ordinary supply curve is consonant with the methods and objects
of this book. In the first place, it expresses the relevant facts in terms
of the units to which we have decided to restrict ourselves, without introducing
any of the units which have a dubious quantitative character. In the second
place, it lends itself to the problems of industry and output as a whole,
as distinct from the problems of a single industry or firm in a given environment,
more easily than does the ordinary supply curve¾for
the following reasons.
The ordinary demand curve for a particular commodity is drawn on some
assumption as to the incomes of members of the public, and has to be re-drawn
if the incomes change. In the same way the ordinary supply curve for a
particular commodity is drawn on some assumption as to the output of industry
as a whole and is liable to change if the aggregate output of industry
is changed. When, therefore, we are examining the response of individual
industries to changes in aggregate employment, we are necessarily
concerned, not with a single demand curve for each industry, in conjunction
with a single supply curve, but with two families of such curves corresponding
to different assumptions as to the aggregate employment. In the case of
the employment function, however, the task of arriving at a function for
industry as a whole which will reflect changes in employment as a whole
is more practicable.
For let us assume (to begin with) that the propensity to consume is
given as well as the other factors which we have taken as given in above, and that we are considering changes in employment in response
to changes in the rate of investment. Subject to this assumption, for every
level of effective demand in terms of wage-units there will be a corresponding
aggregate employment and this effective demand will be divided in determinate
proportions between consumption and investment. Moreover, each level of
effective demand will correspond to a given distribution of income. It is reasonable, therefore, further to assume that corresponding
to a given level of aggregate effective demand there is a unique distribution
of it between different industries.
This enables us to determine what amount of employment in each industry
will correspond to a given level of aggregate employment. That is to say,
it gives us the amount of employment in each particular industry corresponding
to each level of aggregate effective demand measured in terms of wage-units,
so that the conditions are satisfied for the second form of the employment
function for the industry, defined above, namely Nr
= Fr(Dw) Thus we have the advantage
that, in these conditions, the individual employment functions are additive
in the sense that the employment function for industry as a whole, corresponding
to a given level of effective demand, is equal to the sum of the employment
functions for each separate industry; i.e.
Fr(Dw) = N
= SNr = SFr(Dw).
Next, let us define the elasticity of employment. The elasticity of employment
for a given industry is
dNr
Dwr
eer = ¾¾¾¾
× ¾¾¾ ,
dDwr
Nr
since it measures the response of the number of labour-units employed in
the industry to changes in the number of wage-units which are expected
to be spent on purchasing its output. The elasticity of employment for
industry as a whole we shall write
dN
Dw
ee = ¾¾¾¾
× ¾¾¾ ,
dDw
Nr
Provided that we can find some sufficiently satisfactory method of measuring
output, it is also useful to define what may be called the elasticity of
output or production, which measures the rate at which output in any industry increases when more effective demand in terms of wage-units
is directed towards it, namely
dOr
Dwr
eor = ¾¾¾¾
× ¾¾¾ ,
dDwr
Or
Provided we can assume that the price is equal to the marginal prime cost,
we then have
1
DDwr = ¾¾¾¾DPr
1 - eor
where
Pr is the expected profit. It follows from this that if
eor = 0, i.e.
if the output of the industry is perfectly inelastic, the whole of the
increased effective demand (in terms of wage-units) is expected to accrue
to the entrepreneur as profit, i.e.
DDwr
=
DPr; whilst if
eor
= 1, i.e. if the elasticity of output is unity, no part of the increased
effective demand is expected to accrue as profit, the whole of it being
absorbed by the elements entering into marginal prime cost.
Moreover, if the output of an industry is a function f(Nr)
of the labour employed in it, we have
1 - eor
Nr f"(Nr)
¾¾¾¾ =
-
¾¾¾¾¾¾¾
,
eer
pwr{f'(Nr)}2
where
pwr is the expected price of a unit of output in terms of the wage-unit. Thus the condition
eor
= 1 means that
f"(
Nr)
= 0, i.e. that there are constant returns in response to increased
employment.
Now, in so far as the classical theory assumes that real wages are always
equal to the marginal disutility of labour and that the latter increases
when employment increases, so that the labour supply will fall off; cet.
par., if real wages are reduced, it is assuming that in practice it
is impossible to increase expenditure in terms of wage-units. If this were
true, the concept of elasticity of employment would have no field of application.
Moreover, it would, in this event, be impossible to increase employment
by increasing expenditure in terms of money; for money-wages would rise
proportionately to the increased money expenditure so that there would
be no increase of expenditure in terms of wage-units and consequently no
increase in employment. But if the classical assumption does not hold good,
it will be possible to increase employment by increasing expenditure in
terms of money until real wages have fallen to equality with the marginal
disutility of labour, at which point there will, by definition, be full
employment.
Ordinarily, of course, eor will have a value intermediate
between zero and unity. The extent to which prices (in terms of wage-units)
will rise, i.e. the extent to which real wages will fall, when money expenditure
is increased, depends, therefore, on the elasticity of output in response
to expenditure in terms of wage-units.
Let the elasticity of the expected price pwr in response
to changes in effective demand Dwr, namely (dpwr/dDwr)
× (Dwr /pwr), be written e'pr.
Since Or × pwr = Dwr,
we have
dOr
Dwr
dpwr
Dwr
¾¾¾¾ ×
¾¾¾
+ ¾¾¾¾ ×
¾¾¾
= 1
dDwr
Or
dDwr
pwr
or
e'pr
+
eor = 1.
That is to say, the sum of the elasticities of price and of output in
response to changes in effective demand (measured in terms of wage-units)
is equal to unity. Effective demand spends itsell, partly in affecting
output and partly in affecting price, according to this law.
If we are dealing with industry as a whole and are prepared to assume
that we have a unit in which output as a whole can be measured, the same
line of argument applies, so that e'p + eo
= 1, where the elasticities without a suffix r apply to industry
as a whole.
Let us now measure values in money instead of wage-units and extend
to this case our conclusions in respect of industry as a whole.
If W stands for the money-wages of a unit of labour and
p
for the expected price of a unit of output as a whole in terms of money,
we can write ep (= (Ddp) / (pdD))
for the elasticity of money-prices in response to changes in effective
demand measured in terms of money, and ew (= (DdW)
/
(WdD)) for the elasticity of money-wages in response to changes
in effective demand in terms of money. It is then easily shown that
ep = 1 = eo(1
-ew).
This equation is, as we shall see in the next chapter, first step to
a generalised quantity theory of money.
If eo = 0 or if
ew
= 1, output will be unaltered and prices will rise in the same proportion
as effective demand in terms of money. Otherwise they will rise in a smaller
proportion.
II
Let us return to the employment function. We have assumed in the foregoing
that to every level or aggregate effective demand there corresponds a unique
distribution of effective demand between the products of each individual
industry. Now, as aggregate expenditure changes, the corresponding expenditure
on the products of an individual industry will not, in general, change
in the same proportion;¾partly because
individuals will not, as their incomes rise, increase the amount of the
products of each separate industry, which they purchase, in the same proportion,
and partly because the prices of different commodities will respond in
different degrees to increases in expenditure upon them.
It follows from this that the assumption upon which we have worked hitherto,
that changes in employment depend solely on changes in aggregate effective
demand (in terms of wage-units), is no better than a first approximation,
if we admit that there is more than one way in which an increase of income
can be spent. For the way in which we suppose the increase in aggregate
demand to be distributed between different commodities may considerably
influence the volume of employment. If, for example, the increased demand
is largely directed towards products which have a high elasticity of employment,
the aggregate increase in employment will be greater than if it is largely
directed towards products which have a low elasticity of employment.
In the same way employment may fall off without there having been any
change in aggregate demand, if the direction of demand is changed in favour
of products having a relatively low elasticity of employment.
These considerations are particularly important if we are concerned
with short-period phenomena in the sense of changes in the amount or direction
of demand which are not foreseen some time ahead. Some products take time
to produce, so that it is practically impossible to increase the supply
of them quickly. Thus, if additional demand is directed to them without
notice, they will show a low elasticity of employment; although it may
be that, given sufficient notice, their elasticity of employment approaches
unity.
It is in this connection that I find the principal significance of the
conception of a period of production. A product, I should prefer to say, has a period of production n if n time-units of notice
of changes in the demand for it have to be given if it is to offer its
maximum elasticity of employment. Obviously consumption-goods, taken as
a whole, have in this sense the longest period of production, since of
every productive process they constitute the last stage. Thus if the first
impulse towards the increase in effective demand comes from an increase
in consumption, the initial elasticity of employment will be further below
its eventual equilibrium-level than if the impulse comes from an increase
in investment. Moreover, if the increased demand is directed to products
with a relatively low elasticity of employment, a larger proportion of
it will go to swell the incomes of entrepreneurs and a smaller proportion
to swell the incomes of wage-earners and other prime-cost factors; with
the possible result that the repercussions may be somewhat less favourable
to expenditure, owing to the likelihood of entrepreneurs saving more of
their increment of income than wage-earners would. Nevertheless the distinction
between the two cases must not be over-stated, since a large part of the
reactions will be much the same in both.
However long the notice given to entrepreneurs of a prospective change
in demand, it is not possible for the initial elasticity of employment,
in response to a given increase of investment, to be as great as
its eventual equilibrium value, unless there are surplus stocks and surplus
capacity at every stage of production. On the other hand, the depletion
of the surplus stocks will have an offsetting effect on the amount by which
investment increases. If we suppose that there are initially some surpluses
at every point, the initial elasticity of employment may approximate to
unity; then after the stocks have been absorbed, but before an increased
supply is coming forward at an adequate rate from the earlier stages of
production, the elasticity will fall away; rising again towards unity as
the new position of equilibrium is approached. This is subject, however,
to some qualification in so far as there are rent factors which absorb
more expenditure as employment increases, or if the rate of interest increases.
For these reasons perfect stability of prices is impossible in an economy
subject to change¾unless, indeed, there
is some peculiar mechanism which ensures temporary fluctuations of just
the right degree in the propensity to consume. But price-instability arising
in this way does not lead to the kind of profit stimulus which is liable
to bring into existence excess capacity. For the windfall gain will wholly
accrue to those entrepreneurs who happen to possess products at a relatively
advanced stage of production, and there is nothing which the entrepreneur,
who does not possess specialised resources of the right kind, can do to
attract this gain to himself. Thus the inevitable price-instability due
to change cannot affect the actions of entrepreneurs, but merely
directs a de facto windfall of wealth into the laps of the lucky
ones (mutatis mutandis when the supposed change is in the other
direction). This fact has, I think, been overlooked in some contemporary
discussions of a practical policy aimed at stabilising prices.
It is true that in a society liable to change such a policy cannot be
perfectly successful. But it does not follow that every small temporary
departure from price stability necessarily sets up a cumulative disequilibrium.
III
We have shown that when effective demand is deficient there is under-employment
of labour in the sense that there are men unemployed who would be willing
to work at less than the existing real wage. Consequently, as effective
demand increases, employment increases, though at a real wage equal to
or less than the existing one, until a point comes at which there is no
surplus of labour available at the then existing real wage; i.e. no more
men (or hours of labour) available unless money-wages rise (from this point
onwards) faster than prices. The next problem is to consider what
will happen If, when this point has been reached, expenditure still continues
to increase.
Up to this point the decreasing return from applying more labour to
a given capital equipment has been offset by the acquiescence of labour
in a diminishing real wage. But after this point a unit of labour would
require the inducement of the equivalent of an increased quantity of product,
whereas the yield from applying a further unit would be a diminished quantity
of product. The conditions of strict equilibrium require, therefore, that
wages and prices, and consequently profits also, should all rise in the
same proportion as expenditure, the 'real' position, including the volume
of output and employment, being left unchanged in all respects. We have
reached, that is to say, a situation in which the crude quantity theory
of money (interpreting 'velocity' to mean 'income-velocity') is fully satisfied;
for output does not alter and prices rise in exact proportion to MV.
Nevertheless there are certain practical qualifications to this conclusion which must be borne in mind in applying it
to an actual case:
(1) For a time at least, rising prices may delude entrepreneurs
into increasing employment beyond the level which maximises their individual
profits measured in terms of the product. For they are so accustomed to
regard rising sale-proceeds in terms of money as a signal for expanding
production, that they may continue to do so when this policy has in fact
ceased to be to their best advantage; i.e. they may underestimate their
marginal user cost in the new price environment.
(2) Since that part of his profit which the entrepreneur has to
hand on to the rentier is fixed in terms of money, rising prices, even
though unaccompanied by any change in output, will redistribute incomes
to the advantage of the entrepreneur and to the disadvantage of the rentier,
which may have a reaction on the propensity to consume. This, however,
is not a process which will have only begun when full employment has been
attained;¾it will have been making steady
progress all the time that the expenditure was increasing. If the rentier
is less prone to spend than the entrepreneur, the gradual withdrawal of
real income from the ormer will mean that full employment will be reached
with a smaller increase in the quantity of money and a smaller reduction
in the rate of interest than will be the case if the opposite hypothesis
holds. After full employment has been reached, a further rise of prices
will, if the first hypothesis continues to hold, mean that the rate of
interest will have to rise somewhat to prevent prices from rising indefinitely,
and that the increase in the quantity of money will be less than in proportion
to the increase in expenditure; whilst if the second hypothesis holds,
the opposite will be the case. It may be that, as the real income of the
rentier is diminished, a point will come when, as a result of his growing
relative impoverishment, there will be a change-over from the first hypothesis
to the second, which point may be reached either before or after full employment has been
attained.
IV
There is, perhaps, something a little perplexing in the apparent asymmetry
between inflation and deflation. For whilst a deflation of effective demand
below the level required for full employment will diminish employment as
well as prices, an inflation of it above this level will merely affect
prices. This asymmetry is, however, merely a reflection of the fact that,
whilst labour is always in a position to refuse to work on a scale involving
a real wage which is less than the marginal disutility of that amount of
employment, it is not in a position to insist on being offered work on
a scale involving a real wage which is not greater than the marginal disutility
of that amount of employment.